Xem mẫu

Chapter 5 The Rise of Abacus Banking in China How far back in history must one dig to trace the roots of banking in China? Some historians dig all the way back to the Song dynasty period (960–1274), when China had developed an elegant central banking sys-tem. Others start with the Ming dynasty period (1368–1643), when the country had created a commercial economy based on money and credit. And a third group begins with the Quing dynasty, especially the period 1845–1895, the establishment of European and Japanese colonialization.1 Irrespective of how far back in history one reaches, China’s banking has always been a tightly controlled industry with little competition and the risks associated with it, especially in the last two centuries. In the nineteenth century, for instance, banking was tightly controlled by the government and by the guilds, which restricted entry into the industry, fixed loan rates, and rationed credit to their members. In the first three decades that followed the communist victory, China’s banking industry turned into a state-owned industry within a central plan that determined the flow of funds into and out of the industry. In this sense, banking was a routine administrative procedure rather than an active credit risk management operation. Bank lending was primarily extended to the cor-porate sector, and lending interest rates were set according to the form of ownership and communist party guanxi relations, reflecting political priorities rather than risk premiums. This means that banks were not 102 The Rise and Fall of Abacus Banking in Japan and China true banks in the capitalist sense; they were not for-profit enterprises, but government departments with fiscal responsibilities, such as moni-toring the money traffic between the government coffers and the cor-porate sector. Almost all deposits were administratively collected as ‘‘profits’’ of SOEs and rationed to various industries according to gov-ernment priorities.2 The same applies to non-banking institutions such as credit cooperatives, normally run by provincial and local govern-ments. Bank and credit co-op managers lacked the freedom, the exper-tise, and the incentives to allocate credit according to the principles of risk management. In the two decades that followed the 1978 reforms, especially during the high-growth period (1978–1993), a number of state-owned banks were allowed to diversify their operations outside the central plan; a Western-style independent central bank was introduced; efforts were made to separate banking from other business activities and to limit the influence and control of state and local governments over bank financing; and new institutions, known as non-bank financial enterprises, were al-lowed to operate side by side with state banks and credit cooperatives. In spite of these reforms, banks continued to be run as government departments, monitoring the money traffic in and out of the state treas-ury, rather than as true for-profit banks. A large portion of their deposits continued to come from budgetary allocations, SOE ‘‘profit’’ deposits, or ‘‘voluntary’’ salary reductions, and their managers continued to be ap-pointed by government bureaucrats and communist leaders, allocating credit according to central planning priorities. In this sense, bank man-agers played the role of abacus bankers, recording the money flows, rather than true bankers, allocating credit according to the principles of risk management. In addition, as a government monopoly carrying out the sovereign power to issue money, banks enjoyed seigniorage income. This was especially the case during the high-growth era, when rising savings and deposits allowed banks to expand seigniorage, financing the deficits of both the central government and the SOEs. Arguing this hypothesis in more detail, this chapter briefly reviews China’s attempts to develop her economy and modernize her banking industry, especially during the high-growth era (1978–1993), and inves-tigates how such attempts laid the foundation of the Chinese abacus banking system. Specifically, this chapter reviews China’s failed attempts to develop her economy and banking industry in the thirteenth and nine-teenth centuries, as well as in the first three decades of the communist The Rise of Abacus Banking in China 103 rule, and compares and contrasts it with the 1978–1993 high-growth period. As the conventional economic wisdom emphasizes, the welfare of a country does not depend on the quantity and the quality of its resources alone, but on the social regime, the environment that shapes the own-ership relations and the allocation of these resources. Countries with poor economic resources have often prospered because of the right social regime, ownership relations, coordination mechanisms, the absence of strong vested interests, and government regulation. Conversely, coun-tries with rich economic resources have been made poor due to wrong ownership relations, poor coordination and management, government policies, and the presence of strong vested interests, which has been the case in China. A country rich in economic resources, especially human resources, China has missed several opportunities to develop herself and prosper because social inertia and government regulation have constrained the efficient allocation of her resources and the diffusion of new technology. According to Arayama and Mourdoukoutas, China has missed several opportunities to turn inventions into innovations be-cause of a number of economic, political, social and cultural barriers. Powerful guilds and government regulations limited competition and the diffusion of new technology throughout the economy. An open and fluid social structure lured rising merchants away from industry to landholdings and government bureauc-racy. A fair heredity system gave younger sons less incentive to assume entre-preneurial ventures.3 To be specific, China has already missed three opportunities to develop herself. China’s first opportunity to develop dates centuries back, well before Europe, the United States, and Japan pursued their own devel-opment at the end of the Song dynasty, when the country’s economy was more advanced than the rest of the world.4 But China did not cap-italize on this advantage. It did not reach to grasp and colonize the world, as Europeans later did, because her institutions constrained the creation of a world market frontier for her products and the diffusion of new technology. China’s second missed opportunity dates back to the middle of the nineteenth century, when the country unsuccessfully defended herself against the Europeans, the Russians, and the Japanese, who sought a 104 The Rise and Fall of Abacus Banking in Japan and China world market frontier of their own. In fact, China’s defeat by all three powers resulted in the division of the country into spheres of foreign influence. In addition, at this crucial time, China was caught in a fifteen-year bloody civil war known as the Taiping Rebellion, which further divided the country and stalled economic progress. But even after the end of the Taiping Rebellion, government regulations, xenophobic protests such as the Boxer Rebellion of 1900, low labor mobility, and powerful professional guilds in particular slowed the country’s indus-trialization. China’s third missed opportunity dates back to the 1950s and the 1960s and deserves little comment. At a time when China’s neighbors were rushing to join GATT, Chinese leaders were pulling out of it to debate the way to socialism rather than the way to world markets.5 Within this debate, opening up China to the rest of the world was perceived as a danger rather than an opportunity for economic development, and the same applies to private ownership and markets that were replaced by state ownership and central planning. In fact, during the peak years of the Cultural Revolution (1966–1969), China’s foreign trade dropped by 13 percent in nominal terms, while exports accounted for less than 3 percent of GDP.6 The country’s economic resources were placed within a Soviet-style central planning system of nationalized enterprises, farm collectives, pro-duction targets, and tight commodity and resource price controls. Spe-cifically, economic resources were assigned to SOEs and collective enterprises (CEs) and were allocated according to the priorities set by a central plan. The SOEs and CEs were managed by managers recruited from the ranks of both party members and local government officials. This in turn meant that corporate managers lacked the freedom, the in-centive, and the expertise to adjust inputs and outputs to changing mar-ket conditions and to develop new products and processes, a source of sustainable competitive advantages. China’s failure to take advantage of her early opportunities to develop herself is not confined to the real sector of the economy but extends to her banking industry too. During the Song dynasty, for instance, the country had developed a state-of-the-art central monetary system, well before England and other European nations developed their own. Yet China failed to create a modern banking system because of the presence of powerful guilds that limited competition and maintained the status quo. ‘‘Bankers’ guilds were common although not universal. Where they ... - tailieumienphi.vn
nguon tai.lieu . vn